This blog captures interesting news items from around the world for those strained by information overload and yet need to stay updated on global events of significance. The news items displayed are not in order of merit. (The blog takes a weekly off -- normally on Sunday -- and does not appear when I am on vacation, travelling, or otherwise busy.) Joe A Scaria Former Senior Assistant Editor, The Economic Times, India
Tuesday, August 27, 2013
Economy is recovering, pay isn't; Strikes roil South Africa economy; India, Pakistan and the economic theory of democracy
1 Economy is recovering, pay isn’t (Andrew S Ross in San Francisco
Chronicle) You're going to have to be patient.
Very patient. The wage "stagnation" workers are experiencing
even as the economy and job numbers continue to improve is going to last
considerably longer than expected, according to economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
That wage increases
come to a complete halt during recessions and don't recover immediately after
is not unusual. But this time, the freeze and the decline in the real value of
wages is "more pronounced than the pattern observed in past recessions.
The economy has been recovering for four years and unemployment has declined
considerably, but wage growth has continued to slow.
The upside: Could that be one of
the reasons export manufacturing has been doing so well lately - its best in 50
years as a share of the US economy? Yes, according to the Boston Consulting
Group, which says the declining
"cost of labor" is a key driver in America's new global
competitiveness. Companies like Toyota, Siemens and Rolls Royce, are locating export manufacturing facilities here. The
good news for US workers: The shift will create up to 5 million new factory and
service jobs here in the next few years, according to the BCG report.
So, what makes the US
labor market "more attractive than that of all other major manufacturers
among the developed economies"? Labor costs, factoring in productivity,
are far lower; the US market has greater "flexibility" (i.e., less
regulation); and it is "far easier and less costly to adjust the size of
the workforce in response to business conditions."
2 Strikes roil South Africa
economy (Robert Nicolai in Johannesburg Times) Sadly,
our (South Africa’s) unions were years ago trained by then powerful and equally
destructive British unions and are using irresponsible and destructive strike
models. The picture is created that the union bosses do not suffer the dire
consequences they create time and again for members who follow blindly. They
still receive their salaries and drive the luxurious cars paid for by
membership fees.
Admittedly,
companies have in the past been too keen to pay out obscene amounts in bonuses
to their directors and CEOs. But why did the unions not engage in a
constructive manner to have caps and controls to curb this irresponsible
practice?
Workers and unions
should realise that when the mines, factories and the airlines become
uneconomical, eventually the "economic tree" they have been sitting
on will collapse, and nobody will have gained anything. (Erwin Schwentzek, by e-mail)
The biggest strike threats in three years are upon us. I want to point out to the unions that the world's economic growth has
slumped since 2010, and the gold price has fallen from $1980 to about $1390. Protesting
for a 60% to 130% pay increase will not help prices recover. Automobile workers
know that automation and robotic assembly lines may be a large investment to
make, but going on strike for above-inflation increases will make this seem
like the only viable option.
3 India, Pakistan and the
economic theory of democracy (Anjum Altaf in Dawn) A
Seminal book of the 20th century, at least for academics, was An Economic
Theory of Democracy, published in 1957. In it, Anthony Downs applied economic
theory to the study of politics and, among other things, inferred what a
rational government would do given its incentives. At its simplest, the theory claims that a government aims to stay in
power and therefore, if it is democratic, adapts its policies and actions to
appeal to a majority of the electorate.
In India, electoral
strategy demands the amelioration of some constituency at the very least.
Governments could guess wrong (as with the Shining India strategy) but none
could afford to ignore all the constituents all the time. The complete apathy
towards citizen needs in Pakistan is plausible in this perspective. A victim is
the democratic process itself. Unlike in India, the real opposition is no
longer represented by alternate political parties but increasingly by groups
that reject the worldview of electoral politics altogether.
In exploring the
fundamental divide in the politics of India and Pakistan, I often think back to
the 300 years of the Mughal Empire. Half this period was dominated by the six
Great Mughals whom everyone recognises. The other half was populated by dozens
of emperors most of whom few can recall. This was the period dominated by
behind-the-scene king-makers who shuffled puppet emperors at will, retaining
them only for the legitimacy they conferred.
This could explain
how democratic India and Pakistan both remain overwhelmingly dynastic and yet
on different political trajectories. I am tempted to conclude that Indian
politics is a continuation of the first half of the Mughal Empire while
Pakistani politics resembles more the second — the rule of kings versus that of
king-makers.
Of course, in the
age of democracy kings don’t rule till they die or are deposed — they can take
turns in office. From the viewpoint of incentives it makes a huge behavioral
difference if a leader knows he has to remain at home when out of power as
opposed to one prepared to flee abroad to seek a patron. These contrasting
imperatives, incentives, and strategies have led to divergent political
trajectories in Pakistan and India and thereby to the different fate of their
citizens — the one ignored, the other appeased.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment